Grubb summarizes the traditional discussion of how the first U.S. became “Not worth a Continental” like this: “traditional historiography has told us that the Continental dollar was a fiat currency—an unbacked paper money,” and “Congress printed and spent an excessive number of these paper dollars from 1775 through 1780.”
Neville summarizes Grubb’s counternarrative like this:
In May 1775, Congress printed its first $3 million in paper Continental dollars. They were not like modern money nor were they intended to circulate as currency. They were very similar to what are now called “zero-coupon bonds”—bonds that pay no interest, but trade at a discount below their value at maturity. At the time, they were called “bills of credit.” Indeed, like a modern bond, they had maturity or “redemption” dates at which time they could be turned in for their face value in specie or specie equivalents.I suppose one could argue that the story Grubb tells isn’t that different from the traditional narrative he aims to refute: instead of Continental currency being entirely unbacked and overproduced, it was not realistically backed and carelessly issued. It’s not clear if the Congress could have produced better results with more care. After all, they were fighting a war for longer than anyone expected.
The colonies were responsible for using their own future tax revenue to redeem the bills, after which the collected paper was sent to the Continental Treasury to be burned. The system recognized that the colonies and Congress had little ability to raise actual money in wartime. Like all bonds, the dollars represented loans that would be paid back later. The first dollars would be redeemed in four annual tranches between 1779 and 1782, after the war was expected to be over and trade resumed. . . .
The system began to go awry with the third emission of bills. This time Congress failed to specifically set a redemption period. Congress and one of its committees each assumed the other was doing that job, and this important detail fell between the cracks (p. 118). People still had faith in the system, however, and the third redemption period was simply assumed to be 1787 to 1790, the four years following the second one.
Though it was still working, Congress fell into a pattern of rote issuance of currency while losing institutional memory and understanding of its own system. . . . No specific redemption period was set for eight consecutive emissions of dollars and at the end of that time, assuming the original system was still in effect, the final run of dollars could not be redeemed for specie until 1818. The result of this was a very deep time discount. The dollars issued in 1778 were only worth a tenth of their face value in the year they were issued.
This created a serious problem for Congress in financing the war. Congress was now using far more of its dollars to buy supplies on the market than to pay soldiers and the buying power of the newer bills was weak. Congress responded with an ill-conceived plan in 1779 that sent the dollar into a downward spiral. The redemption periods for all dollars were merged and made fungible. Congress announced that there would only be one final emission of dollars and the new redemption window for all outstanding dollars would be contracted and end in 1797. This was expected to reduce the time discount and increase the dollar’s value. It was also intended to reduce Congress’s reliance on debt. The plan, however, would have required the states to raise taxes “eighty times higher than what had historically been feasible.”(p. 168) Nobody believed that would happen and faith in the dollar collapsed.
Nonetheless, accuracy about details matters in economic history like every other sort of history, so I’m intrigued by this corrective.
Grubb is an economics professor at the University of Delaware. His book includes mathematical formulas as well as quotations from the Founders, and Neville says, “the vast majority of it is easily understood.”
Did the book touch on British attempts at sabotaging the system with counterfeiting? I was under the impression that was at least a small part of the problem as well.
ReplyDeleteI too was intrigued by the JAR review. It's tough that the book is so expensive as I will have to try to borrow it from a library. I am interested to see if he mentions the problem of states issuing their own money (as they had before the war). I know Connecticut bills became worthless.
ReplyDeleteFarley Grubb has been working on the issues [!] of the Continental dollar for years, and two of his older draft papers are available online:
ReplyDelete“The Continental Dollar: What Happened to It After 1779?”
https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w13770/w13770.pdf
“The Continental Dollar: Initial Design, Ideal Performance, and the Credibility of Congressional Commitement”
https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w17276/w17276.pdf
The latter states that there may have been concerns about British counterfeiting in late 1777 and early 1778, but the Congress responded by swapping all bills from two emissions with later emissions. His implication is that the effect of that threat was limited, and not on the same level as the redemption concerns discussed in the book.
The book does discuss the state issuing their own notes, but I don’t know how their problems relate to loss of faith in the value of the Continentals.
To say that Grubb's "corrective" is intriguing is far too generous to Grubb. The Continental currency stated right on it that it "entitled the bearer to receive XX Spanish milled dollars or the value thereof in gold or silver, according to the resolution of Congress passed XX" No person accepting these pieces of paper was in a position to get a copy of the specific resolution of the Congress, and in most instances, each successive resolution merely referred to some prior resolution. People accepted these pieces of paper in exchange for goods and services, and were told they could hand them along to others in exchange for their goods or services. They supposedly could be used to pay taxes. Grubb's "corrective" notwithstanding, that's called "money."
ReplyDeleteI'm familiar with the wreckage from all this in the town budget of Lincoln, Massachusetts. In 1775, the town's annual budget was £143. In 1778, it was £196. In 1779, it was £4,200, and in 1780, it was £23,219. No doubt the same occurred widely in other towns. When the war came to a close and Massachusetts reformed its currency, the town treasurer's books starting showing something that had vanished for years -- accounts settled with farthings.
Grubb doesn’t in the least dispute that there was wartime inflation. He argues that the cause of that inflation was different from how it’s typically portrayed.
ReplyDeleteGrubb also seems to say that the Continental notes weren’t meant to circulate at face value, like our paper money, but to trade at a lower value that would grow as the redemption date neared. But when that redemption became too outlandish for people to believe in, even that reduced value collapsed.
At least some of the Continental Congress’s fiscal resolutions were published in the newspapers. I don’t know if they all were. That was similar to how the pre-war colonies operated with their notes.